Thursday, March 18, 2010

The Socialized Medicine Scheme: disregarding public opinion

People can not believe Obama , Pelosi and their progressive followers are ramming through their particular version of health-care reform when public opinion is standing at 75% to "start over".

Maybe this helps explain their attempt to ram through legislation against overwhelming public opinion opposition. Roscoe Pound (early progressive): “ …in the hands of a progressive and enlightened caste whose conceptions are in advance of the public and whose leadership is bringing popular thought to a higher level”. (1)

Hence Obama, Pelosi and their progressive followers are coming right out of the progressive playbook and actually believe they are “enlightened” and the “concept” of their enlightened view of health-care is “in advance of the public”.

'Speaker of the House Nancy Pelosi told an audience yesterday that it was necessary to pass the health care bill to see what was in it away from what she termed the "fog of Washington".' (2)

In other words, Pelosi is stating that her enlightened concept of health-care is what is good for you hence merely pass the bill basically sight-unseen and trust Pelosi as you'll like it.

A final point is that Obama and Pelosi are benevolently giving the public 72 hours to read, digest, understand, and make an informed decision on a 3,000 page bill written in legal jargon regarding a highly dynamic subject. It is a ridiculous notion that an informed decision can be made in 72 hours. Its a ridiculous notion that a 3,000 page bill should not be subject to a long debate regarding all the aspects of the bill.

(1) Roscoe Pound, "The Need of a Sociological Jurisprudence," The Green Bag, October 1907, pp. 611,612.

(2)http://www.aim.org/don-irvine-blog/pelosi-pass-the-health-care-bill-to-find-out-whats-in-it/

Wednesday, March 17, 2010

The Socialized Medicine Scheme: the false choice of central planning

An underlying argument within the health-care debate is that the free market is being compared to a government plan that is somehow likely to perform as the alternative to a free market.(1)

Basically, the free market is a series of individuals, making individual decisions, decisions in their own self interest. That when the zillions of economic decisions are combined, the combination of decisions sets the allocation of scarce resources to competing ends.


The free market intuitively appears chaotic. It appears unorganized. The appearance of a chaotic, unorganized free market however yields the most efficient allocation of resources to competing ends as well as having the attribute of individuals solving for the least expensive, simplest solutions to their perceived problems/needs/wants.

Thomas Sowell has explained the appearance of chaotic and unorganized characteristics of the free market to the ecosystem of a forest. The ecosystem of the forest was not planned. The ecosystem of the forest came about due to a zillion chaotic and unorganized activities that produced an efficient ecosystem. (2)

However, advocates of central planning (government planning as an alternative to a free market) make the assumption that a central authority can better plan and hence create a better outcome than the results of a free market. The problem is:

(a) central planning then supplants the individual. It supplants individual decisions, decisions made in the realm of individual self interest, and precludes decision made by individuals attempting to find the least expensive and simplest solutions to their perceived needs/wants/problems,

(b) central planning then must set prices for scarce resources to competing ends. Regardless of the organization of your economy, resources are scarce and participants in the economy are competing for the use of those scarce resources. We know that no one individual can set a price for more than a few prices that they might be familiar with due to mundane knowledge of a particular product/industry. Then how can a central planned economy (government planning as an alternative to a free market) set the prices for hundreds of thousands of prices? Who is smart enough to set those prices? The very best example is the former Soviet Union where central planners had to set thousands and thousands of prices each and every year that merely caused resource distortion with major surpluses in some areas and severe shortages in other areas, (3)

(b2) going back to Sowell’s forest ecosystem, exactly when should the acorn fall from the tree, where should it land, and should it root and grow or should it rot? Now try planning every leaf, twig, blade of grass and growth/death within the forest ecosystem.

Its counter intuitive to think the seemingly chaotic and unorganized free market creates efficient outcomes. Its intuitive to think somehow intervention by adding planning will result in better outcomes. However, no one individual or group of individuals can plan a gazillion economic interactions or a hundred thousand prices. The ecosystem of the forest appears chaotic and unorganized yet results in an efficient outcome. Planning the ecosystem of a forest is impossible and if attempted produces an inefficient result. Planning economic activity is impossible and produces a highly inefficient result.

Hence the underlying argument within the health-care debate that the free market is being compared to a government plan that is somehow likely to perform as the alternative to a free market is a false choice/argument.

(1)http://www.econtalk.org/archives/2010/03/don_boudreaux_o_3.html

(2) (3) Intellectuals and Society, Thomas Sowell, Chapter 3

Wednesday, March 10, 2010

The Socialized Medicine Scheme: reverse risk management.

The proposed socialized medicine scheme aka ObamaCare fails the axiom of low frequency and high severity within the theory of insurance. Low frequency and high severity risks are the point in the risk management matrix where the insurance mechanism is most efficient and qualifies for deployment. (1) (2) (3)

The socialized medicine scheme's mandated coverage proposal merely moves one toward low frequency and low severity within the risk management matrix. This is a highly inefficient position within the theory of insurance and hence inefficient positions lead to increased costs.

What is the risk management matrix and why does it create an axiom? Why is risk management and self insurance important within the theory of insurance? Why does ObamaCare create an inefficient transfer of risk and hence becomes an insurance cost and health-care cost increase driver ?

The Risk Management Matrix

The most effective use of insurance is to find the simplest and least expensive solution that actually solves the risk problem. That point is found when you have a low frequency risk that results in a high severity result. That is, insurance is most effective when applied to catastrophic events that occur infrequently. (4)

The risk management matrix depicted above is the simplest risk management matrix in the theory of insurance. This particular simple matrix however creates an axiom within the theory of insurance. The matrix can also be expressed as a mathematical formula. (5) The matrix is also a building block to much more complicated risk management matrix used for specific risk situations. (6) (7) (8) The risk management matrix is also used in other disciplines. (9) (10) (11) (12)

Within the matrix you find the combination of high frequency-low severity. The most popular example of this type of risk is your weekly grocery bill. Hence insuring the weekly grocery bill would cost exactly the value of your weekly grocery bill. Using insurance would be ineffective. In high frequency-low severity risks the most effective solution is to retain the risk (self insure) and use loss control and risk management techniques such as using shopping lists, clipping coupons, and shopping grocery store prices.

The next block within the matrix is low frequency and low severity. An example would be replacing a light bulb. The frequency occurs every six months or so and the cost to replace a light bulb is modest. Hence insurance would be ineffective. In low frequency-low severity risks the most effective solution is to retain the risk and self insure.

The next risk is the one that produces high frequency-high severity results. An example would be to build a home within the crater of an active volcano. The event is un-insurable. The chances of loss are high and the severity of loss is extreme. In this case risk avoidance is the only technique available.

The final combination is low frequency and high severity risks. This is the situation where insurance is a viable option. For example, pure risk in the field of property insurance such as fire, tornadoes, and lightning strikes create high severity losses. However, the chances of fire, tornadoes, and lightning strikes are of low frequency and random in nature over a wide geographic area. Hence the risk can be transferred to an insurer for a modest consideration (premium). (13)

Why is risk management and self insurance important within the theory of insurance?

Obviously risk management produces the risk matrix depicted above which indicates when insurance is viable. However, the study of risk management produces techniques such as risk reduction, risk loss control, and risk avoidance. Risk reduction from the loss of lightning strikes would be to install lightning rods. Risk loss control regarding lightning losses would be to install smoke detectors and fire extinguishers on each level of a property exposure. Risk avoidance of lightning exposures would be to not own property hence the property loss exposure is eliminated.
However, if a loss exposure is of low frequency and high severity and hence insurance becomes a viable option, and one decides to transfer the risk to an insurer for a consideration (premium), what amount of consideration (premium) does one want to pay to transfer the risk? Which brings you to another risk management technique known as risk retention. How can the premium be reduced through risk retention?
If the consumer can not avoid a risk, has deployed risk reduction and loss control, and has decided to tranfer the risk by the purchase of insurance, the next question is what amount of a risk can be retained? On one extreme of the risk retention spectrum is to retain a majority of a risk. On the other end of the spectrum is to have a zero deductible if loss occurs. Obviously retaining the majority of a risk results with the insurer having a much smaller obligation which in turn generates a small premium outlay for insurance. A zero deductible coverage results in a larger obligation by the insurer resulting in a relatively high premium outlay.
Hence risk retention is a cost management technique when insurance is the desirable avenue of handling a risk. Higher risk retention results in lower insurance costs.
Why does ObamaCare create an inefficient transfer of risk?
The mandated coverage within ObamaCare requires (mandates) low major medical deductibles and ancillary benefits such as low doctor office co-pays and low drug card co-pays. In other words, the mandated coverage leads to mandated risk retention. It mandates low risk retention and we know the lower the risk retention the higher the cost of insurance.
Low doctor office co-pays, low drug card co-pays, and a low major medical deductible means you are moving within the risk matrix (diagram above) toward low frequency-low severity losses. You are also taking a catastrophic coverage such as major medical insurance and attaching a very low risk rention dollar amount and hence settling for a very high cost. Any movement in the matrix away from low frequency and high severity block to any other block within the risk matrix leads to ever increasing insurance costs. Retaining small amounts of catastrophic coverage leads to high cost insurance. In other words, you are casting a blind eye at the insurance axiom produced by the risk management matrix and further driving up the cost of catastropnic coverage.

Mandated low risk retention and the consequential third party effect and over utilization effect.
When risk retention is very low the group of insureds generally suffer from the third party payer effect caused by the mere existence of insurance. That is to say, insurance causes a disconnect between the provider of health-care and the consumer of health-care. The consumer disregards the cost of a health-care event as the insurance will pay for the health-care event. Hence the cost of a particular health-care event is dismissed by the consumer. If the consumer was paying for the particular heath-care event out of pocket, then the consumer would be very cost sensitive and sensitive to what amount of diagnostic procedures deemed necessary. Insurance has the effect of removing the cost and amount of health-care procedures the consumer demands.
Low risk retention also causes over utilization of health-care resources. If the insured faces a very small outlay in order to access health-care, then the insured is much more disposed to use health-care resources. Low deductibles and/or co-pays cause over utilization.
Freedom to choose.
Risk is a very individualistic problem/measurement. One individual is willing to completely self insure as they have large financial resources. Another individual is willing to retain a large amount of risk e.g. the first $10,000 of a risk as they have the resources to retain larger amounts of risk. Other insureds deploy risk management techniques and can retain more modest amounts such as $5,000. Finally you have a segment of insureds that are willing to pay more in premium as they are either unwilling to retain risk or would rather pay a higher premium as they can not currently retain risk (in effect financing retention).
Summary
Failure to follow insurance theory as spelled out by the axiom of the risk management matrix will cause insurance costs to rise. Mandating low levels of risk retention cause the third party payer effect and over utilization effect which are major cost drivers within insurance cost. Mandated coverage eliminates the consumers freedom to choose.
When risk management is discarded, failure to manage risks causes insurance prices to rise. ObamaCare is a plan, in which the plan itself, will from the very beginning cause prices to accelerate.
Note: the underlying cost driver of health insurance is the cost of the resource known as health-care. However, you can design the insurance mechanism in such a way to become a second cost diver that then magnifies the underlying base cost driver. Designing insurance to reduce cost should be the over aching strategy not creating an insurance design that merely drives up costs.
References

(1) http://www.aiadc.org/AIAdotNET/docHandler.aspx?DocID=319988

(2) http://www.iag.com.au/about/insurance/media/IAG_Insurance_101.pdf

(3)(4) http://www.flatworldknowledge.com/pub/1.0/risk-management-enterprises-an/29742

(5)http://www.atuarios.org/docs/PDF/Intro_Credibility.pdf

(6)http://intranet.icea.es/solvencia/Documentos/Informe%20IAA%20Insurance%20Regulation%20Committee%20February%202002.pdf


(7)http://www.actuaries.org/EVENTS/Seminars/New_Delhi/chapters/page-73to89.pdf

(8)http://www.soa.org/files/pdf/C-21-01.pdf

(9) http://wiki.answers.com/Q/Method_for_computation_of_frequency_and_severity_rates_for_Industrial_Injuries_and_Classification_of_Industrial_accident

(10)https://www.palisade.com/industry/InsuranceModels.asp

(11) http://www.opalesque.com/asquare/452/High_frequency_low_severity_insurance_led_investing194.html

(12) http://www.medicalnewstoday.com/articles/12116.php

(13) http://www.flatworldknowledge.com/pub/1.0/risk-management-enterprises-an/29740

Monday, March 1, 2010

The Socialized Medicine Scheme: who pays for health-care?

One point that seems to be obscured in the current health-care/health insurance debate is the perception that 45% of health care
expenditures are government and 55% are private.

The statistics of Medicare, Medicaid, military, and other government programs make up 45% of health-care expenditures and hence government is 45% of the pie.

That somehow, some way, government pays for 45% of health-care. There is something very wrong with this perception and consequential arguments based upon government currently paying for 45% of health-care expenditures. The argument is flawed as "government" produces nothing and hence is merely a transfer mechanism.

In reality the private sector pays 100% of all medical care expenditures. That is to say, government does not exist without tax transfers from the private sector. A certain portion of taxes are extracted from the private sector by government for the subject of health-care. The government merely acts as a transfer agent of this private sector money.

Hence at the end of the day, 100% of all health-care expenditures are paid by the private sector.